Why we need models to make projections

ChatGPT explains why do we need economic models

GENERAL KNOWLEDGE

ChatGPT, Doğukan CANBAZLAR

1/29/20244 min read

20 euro bill on white and blue textile
20 euro bill on white and blue textile

Economic models are essential tools for central banks to understand and predict the behavior of the economy. They help us to test different scenarios and evaluate the impact of our policy decisions. But how do we use them and what are their limitations?

In this blog post, I will explain the role of economic models in the ECB’s projections, which are an important input for the monetary policy decisions of the Governing Council. I will also discuss some of the challenges and uncertainties that we face when using models, and how we deal with them.

What are economic models and why do we need them?

Economic models are quantitative frameworks that simulate how the economy works. They are based on economic theories and empirical evidence, and they use mathematical equations to describe the interactions between different economic agents, such as households, firms, banks, and governments.

We need models because we cannot observe the future. Models allow us to learn from the past and use the available data to make predictions about the future. For example, a typical projection model can estimate how the recent increases in energy costs would affect households’ and firms’ expenditures, and how wages and prices might evolve.

Models also help us to communicate our economic analysis and policy rationale to the public. They provide a consistent and transparent way of explaining how we assess the current state of the economy and the outlook for inflation and growth.

How do we use models for the ECB’s projections?

The ECB and the national central banks (NCBs) of the euro area work together to produce projections in preparation for the monetary policy meetings. We use a suite of models to forecast the main macroeconomic variables, such as GDP, inflation, unemployment, and interest rates.

The models we use are not unique or fixed. We constantly update and revise them to incorporate new data, methods, and insights. We also use different types of models to cross-check and compare the results. Some models are more structural, meaning that they are based on explicit assumptions about the behavior and expectations of economic agents. Other models are more statistical, meaning that they rely more on the historical patterns and correlations in the data.

The models we use are not perfect. They can never capture the full complexity and uncertainty of the real world. They may also fail to account for some important factors or events that are not well understood or predictable, such as the 2008 financial crisis or the COVID-19 pandemic.

That is why we do not rely solely on the models’ output. We also use our expert judgement to adjust the projections and take into account additional information that is not captured by the models. For example, we may consider the latest surveys, indicators, or news that reflect the current economic sentiment and conditions.

We also acknowledge the uncertainty surrounding the projections and produce alternative scenarios to illustrate how the outlook may change under different assumptions. For example, we may consider the possible effects of a stronger or weaker global demand, a higher or lower oil price, or a more or less severe pandemic.

What are the main challenges and limitations of using models?

Using models for projections is not an easy task. We face many challenges and limitations that require careful judgement and analysis. Here are some of the most common ones:

  • Data availability and quality: We need timely and reliable data to feed the models and calibrate the projections. However, data are often subject to revisions, delays, or errors. Sometimes, we may also face data gaps or inconsistencies, especially for some countries or sectors.

  • Model uncertainty and misspecification: We do not know for sure if the models we use are correct or complete. They may omit some relevant variables or mechanisms, or they may have some wrong or outdated assumptions. Sometimes, the models may also produce implausible or contradictory results that need to be corrected or explained.

  • Structural changes and regime shifts: The economy is not static. It may change over time due to technological innovations, demographic trends, institutional reforms, or other factors. These changes may affect the parameters or the relationships in the models, and make the past data less relevant or informative for the future.

  • Expectations and feedback effects: The economy is not deterministic. It depends on the expectations and actions of economic agents, which may also react to the projections and the policy decisions. These feedback effects may create self-fulfilling or self-defeating prophecies, and make the projections more or less accurate.

Conclusion

Economic models are indispensable tools for central banks to make projections and inform monetary policy decisions. They help us to understand and predict the behavior of the economy, and to communicate our economic analysis and policy rationale to the public.

However, models are not flawless or infallible. They have limitations and uncertainties that need to be recognized and addressed. We do not use models as a mechanical or automatic device, but as a guide and a support for our judgement and analysis.

We are always open to new ideas and improvements. We welcome feedback and criticism from our peers and the public. We strive to make our models and projections as accurate and transparent as possible, but we also admit that we do not have all the answers and that we can always learn more.